Middle Eastern countries between political restructuring and macroeconomic flaws
Over the last two decades, most of Middle Eastern
countries have embarked upon what is called “neo-authoritarian
restructuring”, namely
limited and reversible processes of liberalization aimed to shore up their
authoritarian rule: from the overbearing role of the state in the economy to
cronyism and neo-patrimonialism, state-society relations have shifted from
populist mobilization of the middle and lower strata and inclusive
socio-economic agenda to depoliticization of political discourse and the
consequent diffusion of pro-reform and “technocratic” agenda. In this sense,
elites and middle-classes, instead of being the key actors of political change
in favor of more inclusiveness and participation, seem to constitute the pillar
upon which regimes have restructured themselves. Cooptation of elites aside, to
make things worse is that the only structured and organized opposition is
political Islam, a force of conservation dressed up as progressive.
Why is it so?
One of the biggest flaw is that the Middle East falls
short in terms of macroeconomic integration and thus suffers from several
shortcomings with regard not only to economic performances but also the process
of democratization: the main rationale behind this assumption is that economic
integration would in fact foster democracy and favour institutional change. Macroeconomic
integration is conducive to democracy through several channels: the action of
ruling classes, modernization, human capital accumulation, trade-induced
changes in inequality and, ultimately, the so-called “learning/cultural transmission
channel”.
Though, here I would like to stress few figures about MENA economy stressing how over-reliance on oil has contributed to create several distortions both in patterns of trade and wealth redistribution amongst states.
Oil revenues have created a regional cleavage between
oil producers and non-oil producers. With regard to this, the former has a
stake outside the region and a rentier mentality, while the latter is short of
capital but over-populated and underdeveloped. This has ultimately resulted in
low degrees of competitiveness of local economies if compared to other regions
and high level of capital flight outside of the region. As a
result, oil-rich countries' patterns of trade are characterized by an eastward
vision (China, Japan, India) where the main export goods are petroleum, gas and
petroleum/gas derivative products. Plus, these countries, such as Saudi Arabia
and Qatar, having a downstream-oriented labor force and low levels of human capital, tend to import
capital-intensive and knowledge-intensive goods, such as machinery, equipments
and services: oil has thus ended up deepening technological dependency without
a real absorption/transmission of technology itself. The massive amount of
surplus due to revenues stream is then mostly reinvested in Western financial
markets- in terms of share of fixed-income assets, equities, real estate and
other asset classes, turning oil-rich countries into the biggest providers of venture capital for
high-tech industries in the US. Simultaneously, trend for non-oil producers is
to increasingly trade with EU partners, where the main export goods are
represented by labor-intensive and low-value added products and imports are
made up of capital-intensive goods. It is worth mentioning how these countries
also rely on a steady stream of remittances from citizens living abroad,
especially in the Gulf.
Intra-regional
trade and an across-the-board regional integration with regard to several
variables have
been worsened by the over-reliance on oil. By way of example, over
the period 1980-2000, MENA non-oil exports rose by only 5%, while Latam rate
was well above 350% and South Asia even more than 400%.
To make matters worse,
macroeconomic
fundamentals such as the ratio of external debt to GDP has been growing and
is among the highest in several countries of the region- Lebanon, Egypt, Jordan
and Yemen: as a consequence, resources have been diverted from value-added
investments to servicing the debt. This has led governments to cut public
spending and impose austerity measures across
the region. As a consequence, food riots erupted in Egypt in
2008, when government decided to stop subsidizing food and
bread prices soared. Jordan has experienced the same more than once, when it defaulted on IMF
loan in 1996, and in 2018 again.
Net international investment position of several MENA countries has remarkably improved over the last few years. However, unfavourable regional conditions and domestic political risks deter foreign direct investments, thus worsening both domestic and external equilibrium of such countries.


In light of a likely tightening of global financial conditions, GCC countries followed suit FED decision to cut rates, in order to boost sluggish economic growth and improve credit conditions for private sector. However, shortcomings aforementioned need to be addressed for a sound and inclusive economic growth.
To sum up, over-reliance on oil has worsened intra-regional trade and global integration into the supply chain. A real regional integration would imply lowering trade costs, enhancing factor mobility&product diversification more prices flexibility in terms of factors of production and macroeconomic policies convergence (mon&fiscal).
Last but not least, low increase in income and human capital accumulation due to the aforementioned shortcomings have been short in enabling citizens to better coordinate their actions and push for institutional change. Simultaneously, trade-induced changes in inequality-i.e. the widening of the income gap between skilled and unskilled workers- and consequent more demand for democratic change, have had little effect in MENA region, due to the particular features of the oil-industry and the massive use of skilled-labor force from abroad. Paradoxically, the labelled “learning channel” have had more impact in better living conditions and institutional change- i.e. the widespread penetration of social platforms in the region that have exposed many illiberal countries to the benefits of their democratic peers and have contributed to the Arab Uprising.
Potential for cooperation is quite high: macroeconomic integration could favour institutional change and trade agreements could help in this sense.
(This article is part of a more detailed report. If interested, contact the author)
Last but not least, low increase in income and human capital accumulation due to the aforementioned shortcomings have been short in enabling citizens to better coordinate their actions and push for institutional change. Simultaneously, trade-induced changes in inequality-i.e. the widening of the income gap between skilled and unskilled workers- and consequent more demand for democratic change, have had little effect in MENA region, due to the particular features of the oil-industry and the massive use of skilled-labor force from abroad. Paradoxically, the labelled “learning channel” have had more impact in better living conditions and institutional change- i.e. the widespread penetration of social platforms in the region that have exposed many illiberal countries to the benefits of their democratic peers and have contributed to the Arab Uprising.
Potential for cooperation is quite high: macroeconomic integration could favour institutional change and trade agreements could help in this sense.
(This article is part of a more detailed report. If interested, contact the author)
Comments
Post a Comment